IRV - Sample election - favorite season
|
This article demonstrates the use of instant-runoff voting (IRV) on a small preference poll election to pick a majority winner among four candidates.
It also demonstrates the instability of IRV among elections with three strong candidates, and demonstrates how Condorcet method can pick a strongest majority winner without forced elimination.
Instant Runoff Voting uses rank preference ballots to allow a majority winner to be determined from one ballot from voters and a series of "instant" runoffs, eliminating one weakest candidate at a time until one candidate controls a majority of the votes.
Contents |
Preference poll: Favorite Season
The poll included 76 voters from a summer camp in 2001. The poll question was chosen as favorite season to be easy for everyone to offer an opinion.
Ballot design and Voter demographics
Ballot layout
Here's the ballot layout used. Additional printed instructions merely included the sample ballot below, which is an exact reproduction of the used ballots, except for being marked.
Preferences |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Choice | First | Second | Third | <P ALIGN=Center>
Instructions <P> Place an X in the firstor third choices. |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Spring | <P ALIGN=Center> X | ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Summer | <P ALIGN=Center> X | ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Fall | <P ALIGN=Center> X | ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Winter | |||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Age | <P ALIGN=Center> 15 | ||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Gender | M | <P ALIGN=Center> F | (Circle) |
Age | Male | Female | None | Total |
0-39 | 15 | 13 | 2 | 30 |
40+ | 12 | 23 | 0 | 35 |
None | 3 | 0 | 8 | 11 |
Total | 30 | 36 | 10 | 76 |
Notes:
- Voter ages were from 6 to 82.
- There was approximate equal male and females voting (30 males, 36 females)
- The groupings (under/over 40) were used to divide vote in two somewhat equal subgroups. (30 under age 40, and 35 age 40 or older)
Ballot markings
- All ballots were valid votes (one mark per rank placing), although some didn't follow directions exactly as the instructions requested.
- Markings
- 58 marked X's (as requested)
- 11 marked rank numbers 1,2,3 (in the proper columns)
- 7 marked check-marks instead of X's
- Ranking depth:
- 73 ranked three different choices
- 1 ranked one choice
- 1 ranked two choices
- 1 ranked one choice repeated in all rankings (treated same as one choice)
Notes:
- 100% offered countable rank markings. This shows the concept of ranking preferences is natural and understandable with a simple example ballot.
- 97% of voters were willing and interested in offering more than one preference when allowed.
Election results
Voter subset results
Since the ballot included the voter's gender and age, majority favored seasons could be measured from different voter groups. After the election voters were grouped by two measures (Under 40, 40 or older), and (male, female).
Combinations of these categories allowed 8 voter subset polls. The winners did vary between voter subsets. In all cases except the full set of voters, the plurality winner (first round strongest candidate) was also the majority winner.
Females under 40:
|
<P ALIGN=Center>
Males under 40:
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
<P ALIGN=Center>
Females 40 or older
|
<P ALIGN=Center>
Males 40 or older
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
<P ALIGN=Center>
All Females
|
<P ALIGN=Center>
All Males
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
<P ALIGN=Center>
All younger than 40
|
<P ALIGN=Center>
All 40 or older
|
1 | 2 | 3 | |
Spring | 23 (30%) | 23 (31%) | 39 (52%) |
Summer | 27 (36%) | 29 (39%) | 35 (48%) |
Fall | 20 (26%) | 23 (31%) | - |
Winter | 6 (8%) | - | - |
None | 0 | 1 | 1 |
Total | 76 | 76 | 76 |
You'll notice this All-Voter election had a tie for last place in round two between Fall and Spring. This tie was broken by a rule that says "If there's a tie for elimination, eliminate the weaker candidate from the previous round." In this case Spring was stronger in the first round, so Fall is eliminated.
Counting
Process rules
Ballots were hand-counted.
Process:
- Ballots were piled by first choices
- Each pile was carefully counted and recorded.
- If one choice had a majority a winner was determined immediately.
- Otherwise the weakest choice was eliminated and that pile of ballots was redistributed to second choices.
- Redistributed ballots can be piled next to the pile with the second choice so only the moved ballots need to be recounted.
- Repeat counts for each choice and repeat as needed.
Demonstration
This image shows the full-set election counting process. Ballots are piled by first rank choices in the first round, and transfer votes are placed next to existing piles until a majority winner is found in the third round. (Keeping transfer votes in parallel piles, rather than combining on old piles, reduces the work of counting, and keeping transfers piles separate makes it easier to resolve recount problems when identified.)
Missing image
Irvseasoncounting.png
Issue: Montonicity, tactical voting, and Condorcet's paradox
This example election is a good one to demonstrate the possibilities of paradoxical results that can occur within runoff systems.
The monotonicity criterion for voting systems is the following statement:
- If an alternative X loses, and the ballots are changed only by placing X in lower positions, without changing the relative position of other candidates, then X must still lose.
In this season election, Summer loses to Spring in the final round. However Spring was one vote away from elimination. The question Summer supporters might ask is "What would have happened if Fall had been ahead of Spring - Could Summer beat Fall?"
An IRV election can never answer this question because lower preferences that were not used are never counted.
To answer the hypothetical question of alternative results, we must go beyond IRV and look at the results from the Condorcet method which does not elimination candidates.
Condorcet's pairwise approach
The Condorcet method looks at pairwise competitions and if one candidate defeats all others pairwise, that candidate is called Condorcet's Winner.
The practical value of knowing the Condorcet winner within a IRV election is that if this candidate makes the final-two, this candidate is guaranteed to win against any competitor.
Below is the result from a Condorcet count in IRV round 3 for this favorite season election. Rounds 3a, 3b, 3c are "conditional" rounds, rather than actual elimination. They are done in parallel. Every voter gets one vote in each pair contest.
1 | 2 (tie) |
Peek at |
3a | 3b | 3c | |
Spring | 23 (30%) | 23 (31%) | 39 (52%) | - | 41 (55%) | |
Summer | 27 (36%) | 29 (39%) | 35 (48%) | 43 (57%) | - | |
Fall | 20 (26%) | 23 (31%) | - | 32 (43%) | 33 (45%) | |
Winter | 6 (8%) | - | - | - | - | |
None | 0 | 1 | 1 | 1 | 2 | |
Total | 76 | 76 | 76 | 76 | 76 |
1 | 2 |
Peek atresults |
3a | 3b | 3c | |
Spring | 13 (37%) | 13 (37%) | 17 (49%) | - | 24 (69%) | |
Summer | 8 (23%) | 8 (23%) | - | 18 (51%) | 11 (31%) | |
Fall | 13 (37%) | 14 (40%) | 18 (51%) | 17 (49%) | - | |
Winter | 1 (3%) | - | - | - | - | |
None | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 | |
Total | 35 | 35 | 35 | 35 | 35 |