Reaganomics
|
The term Reaganomics, a portmanteau of Reagan and economics, was used to describe, and decry, the economic policies of U.S. President Ronald Reagan during the 1980s. Reagan assumed office during a period of high inflation and unemployment, and his economic theories are claimed by his supporters to have eventually led to a strong recovery.
Contents |
An Explanation of Reaganomics
Reaganomics or supply-side economics is a highly politicized term, which can be interpreted many different ways. In brief, Reaganomics has two key ideas: lower taxes and smaller government. Or in Reagan's words "government is the problem."
Classical economists such as Adam Smith stress the importance of specialization and trade. For example, if a farmer trades wheat for horseshoes from a blacksmith, then the farmer is more productive and society is better off than if the farmer had attempted to manufacture horseshoes himself. However, classical economists have struggled mightily to explain and offer solutions to the periodic business cycles of boom and bust.
During the Great Depression, Keynesian economists saw the vast numbers of unemployed workers and suggested that the government should "prime the pump" through government borrowing for job creation programs. During the New Deal, the WPA and other programs put this theory into action. Keynesian economists justified this government spending, by claiming through the multiplier effect -- one employed worker's salary will benefit 5 other workers etc. Critics argued that government, being a political entity, is an inept distributor of economic resources.
One school of critics, the monetarists, argued that government can better stimulate the economy by manipulating the money supply. When the economy is weak, the monetarists argued that the government should lower interests rates and increase the money supply. This additional money will seek businesses and start-ups to invest in, via banks and other non-governmental means. The negative effect of an increased money supply is inflation.
After the Oil Shocks of the 1970s, a new economic phenomena took hold: Stagflation. Stagflation combined high unemployment with runaway inflation. Previously, the economy experienced either high unemployment and low inflation, or low unemployment and high inflation. The economy had not experienced both high unemployment and high inflation at the same time. Stagflation meant that if one followed the Keynesian model to stimulate the economy, the government must intervene via new spending programs. The new spending is to be financed either by new taxes or borrowing. On the other hand, if one followed the monetarists, the government had to choose either to raise interest rates to tame inflation and cause further unemployment, or lower interest rates to stimulate the economy and cause further inflation.
A new school of thought gradually arose. It argued that the competitive nature of free markets (free of government regulation) made markets the best means to distribute economic resources. Businesses have to be innovative and create wealth to survive. This anti-government view saw businesses as the "goose that lays the golden eggs" and government regulation and taxes as "strangling the goose". Reagan partially agreed with this anti-government view and sought to stimulate the economy by lowering taxes, financed by borrowing. He argued that lowering taxes will revive the economy. When the economy revived, the increased tax revenues will be used to pay off the debt. Excluding military spending, he argued for broad cuts in government spending, which he viewed as a drain on the economy. Reagan raised military spending, however, as he saw defense as an integral government function, especially in regards to the Cold War.
The disagreement between "Reaganomics" and New classical economics (a modern economic theory which emphasizes that free markets self-regulate most efficiently and optimally) becomes clear with understanding Reagan's exceptional military spending. While taxes were cut and thus endorsing that element of neoclassical theory, massive military spending in the Reagan era resulted in a massive budget deficit. The 1983 deficit reached $207.8 billion, equivalent to 6 percent of the economy, the highest level since the World War II era. This emphatic deficit spending violates neoclassical economic theory emphasis on a balanced budget. Absent this, private actors will rationally expect, as explained by the Ricardian equivalence, for taxes to increase sometime in the future to offset this deficit, and will end up saving enough to offset any increase in consumption resulting from government spending. Furthermore, deficit spending is problematic under neoclassical theory because even if the Federal Reserve lowers the federal funds rate to keep interest rates low and combat this "crowding out" effect, the rational public will see the lack of credibility with this merely fiscal-policy-reactionary monetary policy.
Reaganomics ultimately exists in two forms, actual historical experience and theory. The historical experience of Reaganomics is of increased defense spending and large federal deficits. But the theoretical Reaganomic initiative of smaller government and spending restraint was never implemented, due to a lack of political will.
History
The large, across the board tax cuts initiated by Reagan at the start of his administration were based on principles from supply side economics or the trickle down effect. This was contrary to the demand side economics of traditional Keynesianism, which tries to bring the economy to its existing full capacity by means of increasing demand, primarily through fiscal policy. In the 1970s, many on the right became critical of Keynesianism, which they claimed brought higher inflation without any gains in employment. However, true Keynesianism, which called for deficit spending during recessions and surplus saving during periods of prosperity, was rarely implemented in its totality in American politics, usually because political considerations overshadowed fiscal policy.
The early Reagan tax cuts of August 1981 embodied Reagan's supply-side economics. Economist Robert J. Gordon writes in his textbook Macroeconomics (9th ed. 2003, p. 392) that this was "the most dramatic shift in fiscal policy of the postwar era not related to the financing of wars."
The Tax Reform Act of 1986, which had broad bipartisan support, partly implemented the principles of supply-side economics in a more moderate way. It simplified the tax code and eliminated tax loopholes.
Part of what Reagan implemented was in fact not supply side economics, but rather his own version of Keynesianism. Reagan advocated initiating deep tax cuts and simultaneous increases in military spending, while at the same time claiming that the Federal deficit would be erased. Critics argued that while Keynesian economics promoted the idea of consumers (including the poorest) creating jobs by increasing the demand for goods and services, Reaganomics relied on giving more money to producers by giving tax cuts especially to the wealthiest citizens, who would then create jobs that would somehow find a demand. This type of economic theory has also been referred to derisively as "trickle-down economics."
The belief of Reaganomics that the tax cuts would more than pay for themselves was influenced by the Laffer curve, a theoretical taxation model that was particularly in vogue among some American conservatives during the 1970s. Laffer's model predicts that excessive tax rates actually reduce potential tax revenues, by lowering the incentive to produce. The rise, rather than fall, in government deficits during the Reagan era caused many to question the validity of the Laffer curve. In addition, although the Laffer curve was used to justify tax cuts, its main emphasis was on showing how to maximize government revenues through fiscal policy; because this conflicted with the aim of conservatives to reduce spending as well as revenues, the Laffer curve has more recently been deemphasized by conservatives in recent years. Nonetheless, Federal Government tax revenues did increase significantly following the tax cuts of the Reagan years; it was the dramatic increase in spending that produced the budget deficits of that era.
Before Reagan's election, Reaganomics was considered extreme by the liberal wing of the Republican Party. While running against Reagan for the Presidential nomination in 1980, George Bush had derided Reaganomics as "voodoo economics", a term that held currency long after the recession ended. Similarly, in 1976, Gerald Ford had severely criticized Reagan's proposal to turn back a large part of the Federal budget to the states. After the Reagan election, however, most Republicans endorsed Reaganomics, including Bush, who became Reagan's Vice President.
Support for Reaganomics
Template:NPOV-section A study from the Cato Institute (a Libertarian think tank, which supports many of the premises that lie behind Reaganomics) said:
- Real economic growth averaged 3.2 percent during the Reagan years versus 2.8 percent during the Ford-Carter years and 2.1 percent during the Bush-Clinton years.
- Real median family income grew by $4,000 during the Reagan period after experiencing no growth in the pre-Reagan years; it experienced a loss of almost $1,500 in the post-Reagan years. (source (http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-261.html))
Laffer and Reagan were vindicated by the results of the Reagan tax cuts. Real per capita GDP increased at an annual rate of 2.6% from 1981 to 1989, after languishing at a 1.6% rate during the Carter years of 1977 to 1981. Citation: Louis Johnston and Samuel H. Williamson, "The Annual Real and Nominal GDP for the United States, 1789 - Present." Economic History Services, March 2004, URL : http://www.eh.net/hmit/gdp/
Reagan's supply-side model changed the paradigm of government involvement in the economy. Keynesian economists were at a loss to explain why the aggregate demand increases of the 1970's did not result in improved national economic performance. Likewise, they could not explain how to reverse the shift in the Phillips curve. The Reagan-Laffer-Volcker-Milton Friedman model of improving economic performance by reducing government involvement in the economy has since gained wide currency. President Clinton ran as a "New Democrat": fiscally conservative and trade-friendly. Poland, Estonia, Latvia, Slovakia, Serbia, Romania, Georgia, Ukraine, as well as Russia and Iraq have variations of the flat tax.
Replies to this Defense
Much of the liberalization (telecoms, break up of AT&T, air travel etc.) that many claim helped to reinvigorate the American economy was initiated in the 1970s under President Carter and received broad bipartisan support. For example, deregulation of the airlines was initiated under the leadership of Alfred Kahn in 1978. It can also be argued that liberalization has increased the amount of insecurity suffered by the average citizen, while encouraging wage cuts, the decline of unionization, the rise of profits, and the like.
Reagan's tax policies were accused of pushing both the international transactions current account and the federal budget into deficit and led to a significant increase in public debt. Advocates of the Laffer Curve demonstrate that the tax cuts did lead to a nearly doubling of tax receipts ($500 billion to $900 billion), so that the deficits were actually caused by an increase in government spending. However, old-fashioned Keynesian economics has argued for many decades that any fiscal stimulus helps "pay for itself" by increasing aggregate demand and gross domestic product and lowering unemployment. These forces automatically raise tax revenues and lowers transfer payments such as unemployment insurance. No supply-side effects are needed to understand this story.
The disinflation had been initiated by Fed chairman Volcker before Reagan assumed office. An anti-inflation monetary policy program had been begun by Fed Chair Volcker in the latter days of the Carter administration, but it took awhile to take hold, so that inflation was still near a historical peak around the time of the 1980 elections.
A recession occurred in 1982, his second year in office. Almost no one blames this on the Reagan administration. Instead, it was central to Volcker's campaign against inflation: applying either the Phillips Curve or the NAIRU theory, high unemployment (almost 10 percent of the labor force in both 1982 and 1983) undercuts inflation. Reagan benefited from the fact that Volcker relented (shifting to more expansionary monetary policy) after inflation had largely been beaten. Further, the sudden fall in oil prices around 1986 helped the economy attain demand growth without inflation in the late 1980s.
External links
- Paul Craig Roberts' Essay on Reaganomics (http://www.townhall.com/columnists/paulcraigroberts/pcr20040607.shtml)
- Essay on Reaganomics by Two Proponents (http://www-hoover.stanford.edu/publications/digest/044/eisenach.html)
- Reaganomics after Twenty Years by George J. Viksnins of Georgetown University (http://www.georgetown.edu/faculty/viksning/papers/Reaganomics.html)
Proponent Think Tank Papers:
- The Historical Lessons of Lower Tax Rates by Heritage Foundation (http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/BG1086.cfm)
- Great Myths of the Great Depression by MacKinac Center (http://www.mackinac.org/article.asp?ID=4013)
- Flat Tax in use world-wide (http://www.telegraph.co.uk/money/main.jhtml?xml=/money/2005/03/16/cnpol16.xml&menuId=242&sSheet=/money/2005/03/16/ixcity.html)
- Flat Tax System in Iraq (http://www.washingtonpost.com/ac2/wp-dyn/A50031-2003Nov1?language=printer)
Topics From WWW.EconLib.Org:
- Keynesian Economics (http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/KeynesianEconomics.html)
- Monetarism Economics (http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/Monetarism.html)
- Supply Side Economics (http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/SupplySideEconomics.html)
- Reaganomics (http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/Reaganomics.html)de:Reaganomics